Get Even More Visitors To Your Blog, Upgrade To A Business Listing >>

What’s Innovation Economics All About?

Preface: On Wednesday I successfully defended my dissertation and am now the proud holder of PhD in business economics from KU Leuven. In this post I would like to share the opening chapter of my thesis (title: “Three Essays on Innovation Economics”) with you. It’s a bit longer than what I usually put on this blog. But I think it’s worth a look nevertheless. I don’t only give a brief, non-technical introduction into my work but also go into what fascinates me about innovation economics—a field which still lacks the recognition it deserves in mainstream economics.


“They are more powerful, Sir, than we,” answered Imlac, “because they are wiser; Knowledge will always predominate over ignorance, as man governs the other animals. But why their knowledge is more than ours I know not what reason can be given but the unsearchable will of the Supreme Being.”

Samuel Johnson, Rasselas

In his apologue The History of Rasselas, Prince of Abissinia, the famous English writer and philosopher Samuel Johnson puts these lines into the mouth of Imlac, a loyal friend of Rasselas, who is the prince of Ethiopia. One day, Rasselas grows tired of his sheltered upbringing in the “Happy Valley”. So he decides to escape with a group of trusted confidants to explore the world. As a widely-travelled man, Imlac is the ideal companion for such an expedition. He has been to Syria and lived in Palestine for several years, where he got in touch with people from various lands and cultures—including travellers from the North and West.

Rasselas is curious about Imlac’s encounter with the Europeans. He admires their power and prosperity. “By what means,” he asks his friend “are the Europeans thus powerful?” Imlac’s answer is simple. It is their superior knowledge that spurs their commerce and determines their wealth. By mastering a plethora of useful arts, these nations are able to expand their sphere of interest across the entire globe. And their ideas and innovative ways allow them to live a life of material abundance despite an unfavorable climate they have to endure. Rasselas is pleased with Imlac’s response. He cannot wait to start their journey in Palestine and see the “mighty confluence of nations”, where Occident and Orient meet, with his own eyes.

Johnson, however, keeps the source for such remarkable knowledge and dexterity secret from his character. Instead, Imlac has to refer to the inscrutable ways of God. By contrast, many people of Johnson’s time would have agreed that men are indeed capable of deciphering this secret,* even if progress were only to be made slowly. In that vein, this dissertation constitutes a modest attempt to contribute to the ongoing scholarly endeavor trying to shed light on the sources of science, technologies and innovations that eventually allow societies to prosper economically.

It took years for economists to pick up on Johnson’s idea. After decades of fixation on the accumulation of physical capital—definitely since Marx (1867), but most likely much earlier—endogenous growth theory brought back the notion that increasing living standards are driven by the introduction of innovations and new ideas (Romer, 1996, Chapter 3).

In many endogenous growth models (Romer1990, Aghion1992) the production function of knowledge takes a simple form

stands for the growth rate of total factor productivity in continuous time, but is commonly interpreted as the arrival rate of new ideas (Bloom, 2017). is a measure of research input, for example, the number of scientists in an economy. And the parameter represents the research productivity with which inputs are translated into new knowledge.

Notwithstanding its simplicity, this generic form of the Knowledge Production Function points towards important questions within the field of innovation economics. Do private actors sufficiently provide input to the knowledge production? Or are there market failures that government policies need to address? At what rate are new ideas created in the economy? And how should research be organized in order to maximize its productivity ?

Knowledge and new ideas, as the final product of the knowledge production function, constitute one node in a causal chain that eventually affects many other variables that economists care for (see Figure 1.1). In an endogenous growth model they result in higher exponential growth rates at the macro level. At the firm level they lead to new products and more efficient production techniques, which raise firms’ turnover and profits. Consequently, new ideas are linked to firm entry and survival and therefore determine the market structure in an industry. Furthermore, it is via all these channels that innovation affects conditions on the labor market; and thus influences the well-being of a majority of people in society.

The following chapters revolve around the various aspects of knowledge production and the effects that new ideas exert on the economy. Chapter 2 takes the output of the knowledge production function as given and explores the impact of innovation and new technologies on the evolution of industries. In particular, the chapter is concerned with shakeouts—one of the most drastic developments typically observed over the industry life-cycle. During a shakeout, an initially steady entry rate of firms into a new market suddenly comes to a stop and is followed by a short phase of unusually high exit rates. Within the time frame of ten to fifteen years, the number of producers in a market can fall by more than half (Gort, 1982). Because of this abrupt and drastic upheaval, shakeouts reallocate profits and destroy jobs. A fairly recent example for a shakeout is the global solar panel industry, which entered into a severe consolidation phase at the beginning of this decade.**

Although several explanations for the occurrence of shakeouts have been put forward in the literature, technological factors figure among the most prominent factors (Klepper, 2005). Chapter 2 develops a model of oligopolistic competition in which firms’ adoption of cost-cutting innovations increases optimal firm size and paves the way for consolidation. Strategic considerations, such as accelerated entry due to a preemption motive at the onset of an industry and increased perseverance to sustain negative profits, reinforce the shakeout even further. Previous papers were not able to model such strategic interaction in the dynamic setting of an industry evolution. In that sense, the chapter makes use of advances in economic methodology to provide a more accurate description of the phenomenon of shakeouts in industries that are characterized by rapid technological change.

Chapter 3 shifts attention to the parameter in the knowledge production function. Innovation projects are characterized by high uncertainty in terms of technical feasibility and final market acceptance. Effectively managing this uncertainty poses a considerable challenge for firms. Compared to traditional upfront investment, where the majority of costs are incurred at the beginning of a project, staging of R&D investments has been proposed as a tool for dealing with uncertainty. Because projects are split in several steps and the allocation of financial resources is organized along pre-specified milestones, staging facilitates the abandonment of underperforming innovation projects and allows firms to explore a wider range of opportunities.

Although this concept is appealing in theory, prior literature has pointed to the difficulties firms have implementing the approach in practice (Cooper, 2008). Pre-defined milestones are often not evaluated rigorously, which impedes timely discontinuation of projects and undermines the possibility to examine a larger number of R&D ventures. Given the mismatch between predictions of theoretical models of staging and observed firm behavior, Chapter 3 explores the cognitive decision processes that can lead to suboptimal behavior by R&D managers.

Eventually, Chapter 4 alludes to one of the most fundamental topics in the field of innovation economics. Incentives for private actors to invest in R&D are usually not sufficient to provide , the input to the knowledge production function, at a socially optimal level. This is because innovation entails large positive externalities to society—something that Johnson clearly foresaw in his apologue—and financial markets for R&D often perform poorly. Governments have been called to correct these kinds of market failures by various policy measures, including the distribution of subsidies for innovation projects.

Assessing the effectiveness of direct R&D grants to firms ultimately is an empirical question. It is complicated by the fact, however, that in a majority of cases grant receivers are not selected randomly. Instead, firms need to apply for public support and, subsequently, government authorities decide upon the viability of a proposed innovation project. This two-stage process leads to a selection based on the quality of proposals, which renders the application of standard econometric techniques unsuitable. To date, a large literature has made surprisingly little progress in this regard. Chapter 4 develops an empirical strategy that is appropriate to overcome the problem of selection and thereby provides reliable estimates of the relationship between R&D subsidies and knowledge-driven firm growth.

Having laid out the roadmap for the following chapters I would like to conclude with Imlac’s words:

“Knowledge is certainly one of the means of pleasure, as is confessed by the natural desire which every mind feels of increasing its ideas. Ignorance is mere privation, by which nothing can be produced; it is a vacuity in which the soul sits motionless and torpid for want of attraction, and, without knowing why, we always rejoice when we learn, and grieve when we forget. I am therefore inclined to conclude that if nothing counteracts the natural consequence of learning, we grow more happy as our minds take a wider range.”

With this spirit in mind, I hope that reading this dissertation will stimulate the audience’s curiosity and will be perceived as an enjoyable act of knowledge production.


* In his newest book, Joel Mokyr argues that during the Age of Enlightenment in the 18th century a culture which regarded unraveling the secrets of the natural world as a reverence to God’s creation laid the ground for the subsequent Industrial Revolution.

** See https://www.technologyreview.com/s/428196/the-bright-side-of-a-solar-industry-shakeout/ (accessed on 30 March 2017)

References available upon request.




This post first appeared on Paul Hünermund, please read the originial post: here

Share the post

What’s Innovation Economics All About?

×

Subscribe to Paul Hünermund

Get updates delivered right to your inbox!

Thank you for your subscription

×